Posts

PRESENTATION essay paper

PRESENTATION

ORDER A PLAGIARISM FREE PAPER NOW

TOPIC: FOLATE DEFICIENCY ANEMIA

10 SLIDES TOTAL PRESENTATION

-1 SLIDE OF INTRODUCTION

-6 SLIDES OF PATHOPHYSIOLOGY ( Condensed Slide with proper information)

-1 SLIDE WITH CONCLUSIONS PRESENTATION

1 SLIDE WITH CONCLUSIONS

7 REFERENCES NO OLDER THAN 5 YEARS PRESENTATION

APA STYLE ( Please make sure user proper APA Style

NO PLAGIARISM PRESENTATION

DUE DATE OCTOBER 12, 2022

PRESENTATION

PRESENTATION essay paper

PRESENTATION

ORDER A PLAGIARISM FREE PAPER NOW

TOPIC: FOLATE DEFICIENCY ANEMIA

10 SLIDES TOTAL PRESENTATION

-1 SLIDE OF INTRODUCTION

-6 SLIDES OF PATHOPHYSIOLOGY ( Condensed Slide with proper information)

-1 SLIDE WITH CONCLUSIONS PRESENTATION

1 SLIDE WITH CONCLUSIONS

7 REFERENCES NO OLDER THAN 5 YEARS

APA STYLE ( Please make sure user proper APA Style PRESENTATION

NO PLAGIARISM

DUE DATE OCTOBER 12, 2022 PRESENTATION

Presentation essay paper

Presentation

ORDER A PLAGIARISM FREE PAPER NOW

Economics Collection Philip J. Romero and Jeffrey A. Edwards, Editors

Economics Collection Philip J. Romero and Jeffrey A. Edwards, Editors

For further information, a free trial, or to order, contact: Presentation

sales@businessexpertpress.comwww.businessexpertpress.com/librarians

THE BUSINESS EXPERT PRESS DIGITAL LIBRARIES

EBOOKS FOR BUSINESS STUDENTS Curriculum-oriented, born- digital books for advanced business students, written by academic thought leaders who translate real- world business experience into course readings and reference materials for students expecting to tackle management and leadership challenges during their professional careers.

POLICIES BUILT BY LIBRARIANS • Unlimited simultaneous

usage • Unrestricted downloading

and printing • Perpetual access for a

one-time fee • No platform or

maintenance fees • Free MARC records • No license to execute

The Digital Libraries are a comprehensive, cost-effective way to deliver practical treatments of important business issues to every student and faculty member.Presentation

ISBN: 978-1-63157-614-0

International Economics Understanding the Forces of Globalization for Managers, Second Edition

Paul Torelli

Today’s news media displays an intense fascination with the global economy—and for good reason. The degree of worldwide economic integration is unprecedented. Rising globalization has lifted living standards and reduced poverty, while foreign markets and new technologies continue to present opportunities for entrepreneurs and corporations. Still, economic shocks can spread across the world in minutes, impacting billions of lives. The political framework supporting globalization is now under scrutiny, and recent elections suggest economic policies may be readjusted in the coming years.

This book will help you learn about economics in everyday language, using little or no math, giving you better tools to interpret current events as well as long-term economic and political developments. Modern economics offers a powerful framework for understanding globalization, international trade, and economic growth. You may possess years of hands-on experience dealing with business cycles and foreign competitive pressures, but lack a solid grounding in economic concepts that shed light on the forces of globalization. This book is here to help.

PresentationDr. Paul Torelli is chief economist at Quantitative Social Science, an economic consultancy based in Seattle, Washington. He has worked with leading law firms, corporations, and political organizations, providing economic insights and expert testimony. Dr. Torelli earned a PhD and MA in economics from Harvard University and a BA in economics and mathematics from the University of California at Berkeley.

IN T

E R

N A

T IO

N A

L E

C O

N O

M IC

S , S

E C

O N

D E

D IT

IO N

T O

R E

L L I

International Economics Understanding the Forces of Globalization for Managers Second Edition

Paul Torelli

 

 

International Economics

 

 

 

International Economics

Understanding the Forces of Globalization for ManagersPresentation

Second Edition

Paul Torelli

 

 

International Economics: Understanding the Forces of Globalization for Managers, Second Edition

Copyright © Business Expert Press, LLC, 2017.

All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced,

stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any

means—electronic, mechanical, photocopy, recording, or any other

except for brief quotations, not to exceed 400 words, without the prior

permission of the publisher.

First published in 2013 by

Business Expert Press, LLC

222 East 46th Street, New York, NY 10017Presentation

www.businessexpertpress.com

ISBN-13: 978-1-63157-614-0 (paperback)

ISBN-13: 978-1-63157-615-7 (e-book)

Business Expert Press Economics Collection

Collection ISSN: 2163-761X (print)

Collection ISSN: 2163-7628 (electronic)

Cover and interior design by Exeter Premedia Services Private Ltd.

Chennai, India

Second edition: 2017

10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1

Printed in the United States of America.

 

 

To my teachers

 

 

 

Abstract

Today’s news media displays an intense fascination with the global

economy—and for good reason. The degree of worldwide economic

integration is unprecedented, and rising globalization has lifted living

standards and reduced poverty. Foreign markets and new technologies

continue to present opportunities for entrepreneurs and corporations.

Still, economic shocks can spread across the world in minutes, impact-

ing billions of lives. Citizens are understandably anxious in this age of

macroeconomic turbulence and overextended governments.

Modern economics offers a powerful framework for understanding

globalization, international trade, and economic growth. Many man-

agers possess years of hands-on experience dealing with business cycles

and foreign competitive pressures, yet these leaders may not have a solid

grounding in economic concepts that shed light on the forces of globali-

zation. This book explains economics in everyday language, using little

or no math, giving businesspersons better tools to interpret current events

as well as long-term economic and political developments.

Keywords

economics, human capital, financial crisis, macroeconomics, comparative

advantage, absolute advantage, emerging economy, international trade,

business strategy, economic growth, economic history, international eco-

nomics, political economy, economic development, industrialization, labor

market, convergence, New World, mercantilism, Industrial Revolution,

productivity, technology, capital control, intellectual property, research and

development, productivity slowdown, Adam Smith, factor proportions

model, gravity model, infant industry, import substitution, Asian Tiger,

trade policy, tariff, public choice, rent seeking, trade agreement, free trade,

liberalization, information and communications technology, vertical inte-

gration, supply chain, poverty trap, big push, coordination failure, indus-

trial policy, diversification, value added, managerial capital, skill biased

technological change, population growth, wage inequality, middle income

trap, tradable sector, offshoring, outsourcing, foreign direct investment,

skill upgrading, immigration, wage structure, regulation, competitiveness,

 

 

corruption, democracy, autocracy, socialism, communism, controlled capi-

talism, gold standard, natural resource curse, business cycle, collective bar-

gaining, social insurance, safety net, labor union, Washington Consensus,

multinational enterprise, exchange rate, sweatshop, spillover, human rights,

labor standard, property rights, Dutch disease, extractive industry, negative

externality, pollution haven, greenhouse gas, global warming, climate

change

viii ABSTRACT

 

 

Contents

Preface ……………………………………………………………………………………..xi

Chapter 1 A Brief History of Modern Economic Globalization ………1

Chapter 2 Economic Growth, Convergence, and Trade……………….41

Chapter 3 Theories of International Trade…………………………………67

Chapter 4 Industrialization, Globalization, and Labor Markets ……..97

Chapter 5 Politics, Globalization, and the State ………………………..129

Chapter 6 Poverty, Progress, and Critics of Globalization …………..157

Epilogue …………………………………………………………………………………189 Postscript………………………………………………………………………………..199 Index …………………………………………………………………………………….203

 

 

 

Preface

Now that world wide communications have been established thanks to the authority of the Roman Empire … living standards have improved by the interchange of goods and by partnership in the joy of peace and by the general availability of things previously concealed.

—Gaius Plinius Secundus (Pliny the Elder),

Natural History, 77 AD

“Globalization” is the increasing economic interdependence of all

regions of the world. Made possible through improvements in transpor-

tation and communications, globalization’s driving force is the interna-

tional movement of goods, people, capital, technology, culture, and

ideas. Although silks and spices were traded between Asia and Europe at

least as far back as Greco-Roman times, the process of intercontinental

assimilation wasn’t truly global until the 16th century, when the

Americas became part of world trade and migration routes, uniting both

hemispheres. Several centuries later, the “Industrial Revolution” opened

up new production possibilities and wrought tremendous efficiencies,

overturning the old “snail’s pace” rate of economic growth that had

previously ruled the civilized world. Globalization has played a central

role in facilitating growth, consumption, and higher standards of living,

above all when a major hegemon—such as the Roman or British Empire—

has been in place to combat piracy and provide law and order. Historians

commonly think of the “modern” Western world beginning around

1500, and this book begins with the follow-up to that date. World trade

has grown mightily since then despite wars and depressions periodically

slowing its expansion. The most recent “deglobalization” occurred during

the period from World War I to World War II, when, after a prolonged

period of peace and integration, cracks in the international economic

order fissured, and tribalism and warfare reemerged. Today the degree of

global economic connectivity is unprecedented, even greater than the pre-

vious watershed era prior to World War I.

 

 

To some extent, globalization reflects the progress of civilization and

mankind. Whereas isolation breeds stagnation, cross-cultural contact

brings new influences and technologies, which then vie against the old.

And trade—whether short- or long-distance—yields mutual gains, a fact

that has been understood and exploited since prehistoric times. It is

revealing that the ancient city-state of Athens traded abroad vigorously

and boasted a rich culture, whereas Sparta, its more introverted rival on

the Greek peninsula, did not. Market economies in ancient Greece and

Rome exchanged goods throughout vast regions of Asia and Africa. Far

larger than the territories of any Greek city-state (or even the Macedonian

Empire under Alexander the Great), the Roman Empire was partially

funded by trade and tribute over an immense land network of roads.

Its seagoing commercial ships carried Egyptian grain, Spanish copper,

Greek wine, and Asian silks. Roman traders may have reached China

by sea in the 2nd century AD, and at its peak around this time, the

Roman Empire stretched across all sides of the Mediterranean Sea and

most of Western Europe, ruling approximately 75 million people, with

at least a million living in its capital city of Rome. Roman culture

assimilated Greek ideas about philosophy, politics, art, science, and

architecture, and then modified or sometimes improved upon them.

The exceptional Roman capacity for administration—unmatched in the

West until the British Empire more than a millennium later—provided

order in an extremely violent ancient world, stimulating economic and

cultural development.

Nevertheless, even the greatest and wealthiest civilizations may col-

lapse. Toward its end, the Roman Empire had been weakening for

more than a century, with ineffective governance and a disintegrating

society. Rival generals vied for power and often required bribes to stave

off coups. The Roman government had trouble raising funds and ulti-

mately resorted to devaluing the currency, which caused a destructive

hyperinflation. Wishing to evade the state’s grasping hands, urban citi-

zens and businesses fled to the countryside, helping to pave the way for

feudalism. By the 3rd century AD, the Roman military began to suffer

embarrassing defeats by Germanic forces—part of a rural society the

Romans considered hopelessly barbaric—to the north and Persian

armies to the east. The external threats worsened in the late-4th

xii PREFACE

 

 

century, and in 410, Rome was famously sacked by an army of

Germanic barbarians known as the Visigoths. The Empire continued to

crumble in the 5th century as a number of Germanic tribes conquered

Roman territories. The final act that has traditionally marked the end of

the Western Roman Empire occurred in 476 when a Germanic chief-

tain, Flavius Odoacer, removed the last emperor, a teenager named

Romulus Augustus, from power. (The Eastern Roman Empire, later

known as the Byzantine Empire, survived until the 1453 conquest of

Constantinople by Ottoman Turks.) For centuries afterward, during the

period of conflict, disorder, and migration in Europe commonly known

as the “Dark Ages,” Middle Eastern merchants came to dominate trade

routes along the crossroads region linking the Asian and European econ-

omies. Knowledge of many key technologies disappeared, and there

were relatively few cultural achievements coming out of the West.

Written by an American economist, this book focuses on the experi-

ence of the West, albeit without ignoring the East. Based on the most

recent academic research, it provides a brief readable introduction to the

economic forces of globalization for an audience of modern managers

and executives who may have little or no background in formal eco-

nomics. By presenting key economic concepts that have withstood the

test of time, this book offers valuable insights to business practitioners

grappling with the effects of globalization, new technology, and interna-

tional trade on their organization and work force. It is conscious of the

present economic climate which follows several decades of rapid globali-

zation, and its content can provide structure for an undergraduate or

graduate course in business. Each chapter may engender classroom or

workplace discussions, given the inherent complexity of the subject mat-

ter. Although this book is not meant to be historically exhaustive by any

means, it endeavors to spark an interest in world economic history

among readers. It can be supplemented with current materials from news-

papers such as the Wall Street Journal, New York Times, and Financial Times, as well as insightful magazines such as the Economist. Relevant case studies from the Harvard Business School Press (which can be found

online) are presented at the end of each chapter.

Economists commonly concentrate on international trade integra-

tion as the primary feature of globalization, as it is relatively easy to

PREFACE xiii

 

 

measure and analyze. This book is no exception: it emphasizes the

effects of international trade as opposed to global financial liberalization

and integration. Theoretical discussions of monetary issues—such as

exchange rates, balance of payments, and optimal currency unions—are

generally ignored. This is partly because financial and monetary theories

remain controversial among economists, but more importantly—and in

line with how economics is actually taught in universities today—this book

reflects the philosophy that it is better to learn the fundamental structural

factors driving economic events first, because complex financial and mone-

tary factors can be studied later. Monetary theories of business cycle fluc-

tuations and financial crises are traditionally based on behavioral theories

of how money, credit, prices, and output interact. Interested readers are

referred to the works of John Maynard Keynes, Charles Kindleberger, and

Barry Eichengreen, among others, some of which are mentioned in

“Further Reading” sections at the end of each chapter.

Further Reading

Amemiya, T. (2007). Economy and economies of Ancient Greece. New York, NY: Routledge.

Beckwith, C. (2009). Empires of the silk road: A history of Central Eurasia from the Bronze Age to the present. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Bernstein, W. (2004). The birth of plenty: How the prosperity of the modern world was created. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.

Bordo, M., Taylor, A., & Williamson, J. (2005). Globalization in historical per- spective. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

Braudel, F. (1995). A history of civilizations. New York, NY: Penguin. Davies, N. (2011). Vanished kingdoms: The rise and fall of states and nations.

New York, NY: Viking. Goldsworthy, A. (2009). How Rome fell: Death of a superpower. New Haven,

CT: Yale University Press. Hansen, V. (2012). The Silk Road: A new history. Oxford, England: Oxford

University Press. Jennings, J. (2014). Globalizations and the ancient world. Cambridge, England:

Cambridge University Press. Maddison, A. (2007). Contours of the world economy 1-2030 AD: Essays in

macro-economic history. Oxford, England: Oxford University Press.

xiv PREFACE

 

 

North, D. (2010). Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Richard, C. (2010). Why we’re all Romans: The Roman contribution to the west- ern world. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield.

Stearns, P. (2009). Globalization in history. New York, NY: Routledge. Temin, P. (2012). The Roman market economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Uni-

versity Press.

PREFACE xv

 

 

 

CHAPTER 1

A Brief History of Modern Economic Globalization

Introduction

The urge to exchange goods and services is a fundamental characteristic of

any economy, and human beings have traded across far-flung locales for

millennia. Archaeologists point to Mesopotamia, in modern day Iraq, as

the place where Western civilization began. The ancient Sumerians of

Mesopotamia were inveterate traders with a culture that featured writing,

mathematics, laws, and cities. Over the subsequent centuries, trade net-

works and economic integration grew to cover ever-greater regions of the

Eurasian landmass, depending on the stability and reach of existing polit-

ical regimes. The 4,000-mile “Silk Road,” a network of overland trade

routes connecting China to the Mediterranean, transferred goods and

spread ideas between the East and the West. Many scholars believe these

exchanges constitute the nascent beginnings of intercontinental economic

globalization within the “Old World.”

The rise of the Mongol Empire under Genghis Khan in the early-13th

century—several centuries before the discovery of the “New World”—led

to the “Pax Mongolica” (or Mongol Peace). The Mongol conquests unified

Central Eurasia, promoting overland trade all the way from Western

Europe to East Asia. According to some contemporary accounts of this era,

the Silk Road was safe for travel and business. Under the Pax Mongolica,

Europeans such as the Venetian merchant Marco Polo came to China

for Asian silks and spices. Chinese silks sold in Italy for no less than three

times their purchase price in China, and the markets of Constantinople

contained all the wares of Asia. Because information flowed east to west

and vice-versa, Europeans took advantage of many Chinese inventions

and scientific concepts. Meanwhile, the Mongols—who lacked culture

 

 

and craft but possessed a taste for fine textiles and other riches—forcibly

transplanted European artisans and Middle Eastern weavers back to Asia.

The Mongol Empire provided a conduit not only for trade but also for

disease. In the mid-14th century, the Silk Road trade route aided the trans-

mission of the plague from China to Europe. Economic integration

declined, and the Mongols, possessing more skill in conquest than in gov-

ernance, lost their grip on power shortly thereafter. As Europe’s population

recovered, feudalism gave way to nation-states, and seafaring adventurers

discovered the New World, sparking an unprecedented globalization

boom. Since then, the volume of world trade and degree of global eco-

nomic integration has trended upward at an increasing pace. Few today

believe that international economic integration will be reversed, although

the period from World War I to World War II was the great exception,

proving that disintegration is possible, and that taking part in globalization

is a choice that nations face, not an imperative.

Mercantilist World View

Modern economists trace their field’s origins back to Adam Smith’s

1776 Wealth of Nations. This treatise examined trade’s role in facilitating specialization and the division of labor, thereby increasing productivity

and promoting prosperity. Its content was in opposition to the popular

mercantilist beliefs that reached their apogee in the 17th century. Mercan-

tilism of that era was a nationalistic doctrine promoted by a diffuse group

of pamphleteers who advocated for specific interests and industries. Mer-

cantilist writers were usually appreciative of international trade—just not

unfettered free trade. In the 16th century,

Presentation essay paper

Presentation

ORDER A PLAGIARISM FREE PAPER NOW

Industrialization, Globalization,

and Labor Markets Introduction

In standard models of labor markets, wages are equal to the “marginal product” (or

incremental output) of an additional unit of labor. In other words, the amount a

worker earns is equal to the amount he or she can produce. Intuitively, firms take

on workers until the productivity of their last hire is equal to the market wage rate.Presentation

If the wage rate were below productivity, firms would find it profitable to hire

more workers, whereas if the wage were above productivity, firms would have an

incentive to shed workers. Under this reasoning, more productive workers get paid

more, which implies that labor productivity growth ultimately leads to wage

growth in the long term. Indeed, empirical evidence shows labor costs and labor

productivity are strongly related across nations.

Now consider the neoclassical growth model, where economic growth is driven byPresentation

physical capital accumulation, technology, and human capital. These factors all

increase labor productivity, and hence, labor demand. In essence, as economies

grow, more manpower is required, so labor demand increases. Provided the labor

supply doesn’t expand too quickly from pop- ulation growth, economic growth

leads to wage growth in a wide class of economic models. With the above primer

in mind, this chapter investi- gates the impact of globalization on labor markets

across developing and developed countries. It discusses common economicPresentation

models of develop- ment, industrialization, and industrial policies, focusing on

domestic labor market consequences, and it broadly analyzes the experiences of

American, Mexican, Chinese, and Indian labor markets in recent decades.

Lewis Model of Development

After World War II, many nations were rebuilding from the war or had just won

independence. This climate sparked a renewed interest in eco- nomic theories of

development. At the same time the neoclassical growth model was being

developed, in 1954 Sir Arthur Lewis devised what came to be known as the Lewis

two-sector “dual” model of development, for which he later won a Nobel Prize.

Born in St. Lucia, then a British colonial territory in the Caribbean, Lewis was

deeply knowledgeable about eco- nomic history. He had a lifelong interest inPresentation

practical development policy and spent years in the field, advising Ghana and

developing Caribbean nations. As opposed to the broader neoclassical growth

model, which describes long-run growth and the behavior of emerging economies

 

 

as they catch up to leading economies, the Lewis model shows how a traditional

agricultural economy transforms into a modern manufacturing and service-based

economy. According to Lewis, an abundant supply of cheap labor allows

underdeveloped agrarian economies to accumulate capital and industrialize.

While investigating the early Industrial Revolution in Britain, Lewis was puzzled

that wages had stagnated while savings, investment, and prof- its multiplied.

(Later research by other scholars challenged Lewis’s reading of those trends; some

have argued that, at least during the late Industrial Revolution, wages soared,Presentation

spurring laborsaving inventions in England.) Lewis remarked that in standard

economic models, a surge in investment should have resulted in rising labor

productivity and wages, alongside declining returns to capital. He cleverly solved

the conundrum by making several alternate assumptions. First, he assumed

developing economies possess two sectors, agricultural, where most of the

population initially resides, and urban, where industrial activity takes place.

Second, reminis- cent of the economics of Reverend Malthus, he assumed that in

the agri- cultural sector, labor was effectively in unlimited supply. This implied

that agricultural labor productivity was minimal and wages remained at a

subsistence level. Third, he proposed that the burgeoning urban sector possessed

higher productivity with substantial capital, akin to the neoclas- sical growth

model economy. In the Lewis model, capitalists in the urban sector pay relatively

low wages because it only takes a slight premium oversubsistence wages to attract

workers from the country to the city. Capital accumulation and technological

advancement cause productivity to increase in the urban sector, yet urban wagesPresentation

stay relatively flat due to the rural labor surplus.

The upshot is that urban business owners are able to make ample prof- its and

invest heavily in new capital. Over time, the urban sector expands and modern

manufacturing and service industries emerge. Urban labor demand stays strong

and workers from the agricultural sector keep moving to the big city. However,

because urban growth steadily diminishes the amount of labor in the countryside,

the economy eventually reaches a “turning point” (or labor supply constraint)

when rural labor is nearly exhausted. After the turning point occurs, wages in the

city begin to increase even faster, eating into industrialist profits. (Think of China

today.) By this time, most of the population lives in urban areas, and going

forward, the neoclassical growth model is broadly applicable. After the turning

point, labor disputes and strikes increase, since workers have new- found

bargaining power. Future generations become used to greater con- sumption levels

and have higher workplace expectations, inviting collective bargaining and

burgeoning regulatory regimes. Governments start financ- ing more basic

education, which increases human capital and enhances productivity. As the

economy becomes prosperous and more advanced, it orients itself toward services

 

 

and internal consumption, with an export sector that produces increasingly

complex goods requiring substantial skill and technology.

Unlike traditional models, the Lewis model illustrates why: (1) megacities in

developing nations have shantytowns on their outskirts, full of unskilled workers

from the countryside looking for urban work; (2) in developing economies,

workers typically prefer regular wage employment to self-employment but often

cannot find it; and (3) many individuals work full time yet are still poor. These

observations are con- sistent with the Lewis model. Due to the rural labor surplus,

the model predicts that developing countries feature low wages that do not

increase much initially as the population moves to cities. After the turning point,

wages may grow much faster. Higher incomes can be saved, supporting

investment and further economic growth. On the other hand, the financial sector in

emerging economies is often dreadfully underdeveloped. Worker may find few

safe havens to keep their savings, and it may be difficult to obtain loans for new

business ventures, even at very high interest rates. Due to deficient financial

intermediary institutions and a dearth of domestic savings, developing nations may

require foreign capital to finance indus- trial investment and economic growth. In

the 19th century, American states borrowed heavily from wealthier nations

abroad—to build canals, for example—and sometimes ended up defaulting.

Poverty Traps, Big-Pushes, and Take-Offs

During the 1950s, around the time that Lewis was formulating his two- sector

theory, another famous model dominated development economics. Called the

“big-push” model of economic development, it arose out of a paper by Paul

Rosenstein-Rodan in 1943. Its key insight was that some poor countries exist in

“poverty traps” which require substantial invest- ment to jump start economic

growth. The big-push model of development is based on the idea that poor

economies suffer from “coordination fail- ures,” meaning private sector

organizations lack the necessary incentives to adopt modern production techniques

and achieve economies of scale. Unless there is an expectation that other firms

will similarly invest in industrialization, there is unlikely to be sufficient consumer

demand and capital funding to make such costly investments worthwhile. Each

com- pany only kicks-off investment projects if the others do, yet it is difficult to

get companies to start investing all of a sudden. (Some call this type of conundrum

a “chicken or egg” problem, because it isn’t clear how one can come into being

without the other existing first.)

Consider the plight of a poor farmer in a traditional subsistence econ- omy. He

would like to improve the yield of his soil with fertilizers, so the economy requires

either the construction of a fertilizer factory or the import of foreign fertilizer.

However, a factory requires infrastructure (such as roads, electric power, and

 

 

water supply), trucks, fuel, capital investment, engineers, and packaging. And

importing requires a dock, roads, trucks, fuel, and credit from bankers. It isn’t at

all likely that any single farmer would be able to carry out either of these

scenarios. Mean- while, ordinary citizens do not invest in education and training

because there are no jobs available that would make use of higher level skills.

Foreign engineers, bankers, and lawyers may be required to fill the domes- tic

void. In this view, what is needed is a powerful entity—typically a national

government—to coordinate the decisions of firms and house- holds to overcome

market synchronization failures. This coordinating entity would provide

investment funding to the private sector to build: (1) an industrial base with new

technologies and (2) education and train- ing facilities for workers. The economy

would then “take off,” driven by consumer demand. One classic example of a big-

push success story is Meiji Japan, when the Japanese government—propelled by

Japan’s “zaibatsu,” or pyramidal business groups—coordinated a rapid

industrialization in the final decades of the 19th century. Another instance is the

postwar American South, which received a big-push catalyst from public capital

investments to build schools, hospitals, roads, dams, and power plants during the

Great Depression and World War II.

If the least developed economies are stuck in poverty traps and face massive

coordination failures, they probably won’t be able to solve their problems on their

own since tax bases and state coffers are too small. Development economists have

frequently argued that the least devel- oped economies need foreign aid and loans

(such as from the World Bank or International Monetary Fund) to get out of this

rut. These funds could be used for private sector investment and public goods like

infrastructure, education, and health care. If an economy is capable of supporting

an increasing returns industry, then the case for massive injections of capital is all

the stronger. Large-scale industries can support worker payrolls, drive export

growth, and provide tax revenues to gov- ernments. With substantial foreign

investment, an economy stuck in a poverty trap will hopefully begin to grow.

Then, after it has left the trap, growth will be self-sustaining. Ideally the economy

would obtain access to foreign technologies, build domestic universities, and

eventually con- duct its own research and development. Labor productivity would

grow quickly, resulting in higher wages for both skilled and unskilled workers.

The influential mid-20th century economist Alexander Gerschenkron argued that,

driven by heavy state involvement—and the adoption of foreign methods and

borrowed technology, as stressed by American economist Thorstein Veblen—

backward countries could accelerate eco- nomic growth.

Big-push development theory was the leading concept in development economics

throughout the 1950s and 1960s. It was thought that econo- mies all went through

the same stages of growth. The proper mix of sav- ings, investment, and foreign

aid was all that was needed to power them. International development aid was

 

 

intended to catalyze emerging econo- mies and ignite self-sustaining growth. Big-

push thinking lost favor during the 1970s and 1980s, in part due to the apparent

failure of foreign invest- ment and aid to produce significant increases in

economic growth and productivity in Africa. The theory was displaced by market

liberalization and privatization policies, although big-push ideas—sometimes

combined with market liberalization—have reemerged over the past couple

decades, chiefly among economists in advanced nations who stress the importance

of foreign aid.

By and large, modern empirical studies lend little clear support to the big-push

model. If the poorest economies are stuck in poverty traps and a big-push effort is

essential to kindling growth, then developing nations receiving aid should grow

faster than economies receiving little or no aid. Yet if anything, the cross-country

data indicate the opposite is true. Also, the handful of countries that successfully

underwent major growth transitions—or take-offs—over the past half century

were disproportion- ately in East Asia. Despite the fact that their governments

were instrumen- tal in fostering economic growth, these economies only received

a small amount of foreign aid on average. Big-pushes require massive investment,

but with the exception of Singapore and possibly Hong Kong, investment was not

exceptionally high at the beginning of East Asian take-offs.

Some big-push proponents have remarked that over the past two cen- turies, the

output gap between the richest and poorest countries has gotten much larger,

meaning these two groups have diverged. By and large, the wealthiest economies

prospered while the poorest stagnated. Although it is possible many poor countries

(particularly in Africa) have been stuck in a classic poverty trap, the actual growth

trends are, at best, only broadly con- sistent with the need for big-pushes. Recent

studies suggest weak institutions are probably a better explanation for the

lackluster growth of the poorest economies over this long time frame. Many critics

of foreign aid to sub- Saharan Africa and other poor regions point to studies

showing a negative statistical relationship between the volume of foreign aid and

subsequent economic growth. Based on this evidence, they argue that aid erodes

insti- tutional quality by increasing the power of kleptocratic elites and corrupt

government officials, and in practice, is really just a windfall for despots.

Proponents of foreign aid contend that such destructive outcomes can be prevented

through enhanced monitoring and accountability measures.

Industrial Policy

Big-push investment projects—whether financed with tax revenues, domestic

savings, or foreign credit—are a form of “industrial policy.” By definition,

industrial policies consist of sector-specific initiatives that enhance

industrialization, productivity growth, and national competitive- ness, all aiming to

 

 

promote the national interest. These policies have tradi- tionally involved

economic restructuring in the industrial, manufacturing, and agricultural export-

oriented sectors. Half a century ago, in line with big-push thinking, development

economists believed that forceful govern- ment interventions were the key to

industrial policy. Based on historical evidence and theoretical developments,

economists today are more likely to stress the importance of industrial policy

driven by private initiative, albeit within a framework supported by the public

sector. These concepts are potentially relevant to all economies, whether advanced

or developing, and the optimal set of industrial policies differs according to the

circum- stances of each economy.

Although implementing industrial policies involves controversy and risk, the

rewards can be enormous. Government officials and private firms can work

closely together to implement efficient restructurings, though in practice, these

alliances may also increase corruption. One classic industrial policy is the

subsidization of a brand new industry: governments may pro- vide infrastructure,

low-cost capital, or even protection from overseas com- petitors in the form of

trade barriers. For example, in recent years China has given favored domestic

firms free land, subsidized energy, low-interest loans, insider information, and

favorably rigged bids. If successful, new industries take off, resulting in demand

spillovers across other domestic sectors, which generate even greater employment

and output.

Critics argue that industrial policies are likely to be disastrous because

governments are poor candidates to predict which industries will thrive.

For one, the venture capital industry has trouble forecasting which projects will

ultimately be successful, so it is difficult to see how a government agency, using

taxpayer funds, could do better. Even if the bureaucracy in charge of an industrial

policy project is honest and relatively efficient, critics contend that it probably

wouldn’t be able to execute ventures with nearly the same resourcefulness and

drive as private sector businesses. Furthermore, once an industrial policy directive

is underway, it is difficult to gauge the success of long-term projects or thwart the

rent-seeking efforts of powerful private sector agents. There is certainly evidence

from past industrial policy failures to support these charges. With its “Cassa del

Mezzogiorno” (or Fund for the South) program to develop and industri- alize its

backward southern economy after World War II, Italy experienced tremendous

waste and corruption. At least a third of the funds were esti- mated to have been

squandered. Factories never became operational and sham enterprises existed only

to collect government grants. In post- colonial Africa, bureaucracies have often

been dominated by political, tribal, and family influence, leading to a long list of

failed industrial policy projects across many nations.

 

 

Other countries have succeeded with their industrial policies in the past. Japan’s

“Ministry of International Trade and Industry” (MITI) coor- dinated industrial and

trade policy after World War II, supporting the development of the petrochemical

industry in the 1950s, the electronics industry in the 1960s, the computer industry

in the 1970s, and the biotechnology and aviation industries in the 1980s and

1990s. China has picked a number of winners in its manufacturing sector. If not

for generous public assistance, it is possible that some Chinese industries would be

much smaller or not exist at all today. Chile is another exam- ple. Chilean grapes,

forest products, and salmon are all successful export industries that were aided by

government assistance and subsidies. Industrial policies may take different forms

within an industry over time. In Mexico, the motor vehicle and computer

industries were ini- tially supported by import-substitution policies that

encouraged local production to take the place of imports. Later they benefitted

from pref- erential tariff policies under NAFTA. Finally, governments must mon-

itor subsidized industries and quickly phase out the support of failures. This is

difficult to do in practice. East Asian governments have been much more

successful than Latin American governments at this aspect of industrial policy.

Restructuring, Diversification, and Development

Economic development requires a shift from subsistence agriculture to modern

industries exhibiting higher productivity levels. At low levels of development,

economic growth entails a decreasing degree of concentration—meaning

production becomes more diversified across sectors. At this stage of development,

sectors within an economy exhibit vastly uneven productivity and growth.

Entrepreneurs and businesses are discovering their own cost structures and

learning how to improve their bottom line.

Research shows that when economies reach per capita income of approximately

$15,000 to $20,000 in today’s American dollars, they reach a tipping point: their

economies start to become more concentrated and less diversified. At this stage of

growth, economies have found their com- parative advantages, and they are

leveraging economies of scale. Their export sector is usually well developed,

concentrating on a small number of manufactured goods that are highly popular

with buyers around the world. Historical patterns of production, resource

advantages, superior entrepreneurship, and pure chance all play vital roles in

determining the basket of goods an economy specializes in producing and

exporting. As these economies grow and prosper, their production shifts to

complex goods that exhibit complementarities in production—meaning high-

quality labor and capital inputs are necessary—and provide greater value-added.

In economies that develop successfully, labor moves from less produc- tive

activities to more productive ones, raising output and wages. This can be achieved

 

 

by sectoral reallocations, such as transitioning from agriculture to manufacturing.

In fact, labor in developing countries is about three to four times more productive

in manufacturing than in agriculture, and wages are consequently higher. By

successfully expanding the manufactur- ing sector, a developing economy can

raise productivity and output, even in the absence of major technological

improvements. Over the past several decades, this is precisely what happened in

developing Asian nations such as China, India, the Philippines, and Indonesia.

These economies much more successful than Latin American governments at this

aspect of industrial policy.

Restructuring, Diversification, and Development

Economic development requires a shift from subsistence agriculture to modern

industries exhibiting higher productivity levels. At low levels of development,

economic growth entails a decreasing degree of concentration—meaning

production becomes more diversified across sectors. At this stage of development,

sectors within an economy exhibit vastly uneven productivity and growth.

Entrepreneurs and businesses are discovering their own cost structures and

learning how to improve their bottom line.

Research shows that when economies reach per capita income of approximately

$15,000 to $20,000 in today’s American dollars, they reach a tipping point: their

economies start to become more concentrated and less diversified. At this stage of

growth, economies have found their com- parative advantages, and they are

leveraging economies of scale. Their export sector is usually well developed,

concentrating on a small number of manufactured goods that are highly popular

with buyers around the world. Historical patterns of production, resource

advantages, superior entrepreneurship, and pure chance all play vital roles in

determining the basket of goods an economy specializes in producing and

exporting. As these economies grow and prosper, their production shifts to

complex goods that exhibit complementarities in production—meaning high-

quality labor and capital inputs are necessary—and provide greater value-added.

In economies that develop successfully, labor moves from less produc- tive

activities to more productive ones, raising output and wages. This can be achieved

by sectoral reallocations, such as transitioning from agriculture to manufacturing.

In fact, labor in developing countries is about three to four times more productive

in manufacturing than in agriculture, and wages are consequently higher. By

successfully expanding the manufactur- ing sector, a developing economy can

raise productivity and output, even in the absence of major technological

improvements. Over the past several decades, this is precisely what happened in

developing Asian nations such as China, India, the Philippines, and Indonesia.

These economies

 

 

At the other extreme, the absence of managerial capital in emerging economies

can impede economic growth and entrepreneurship. As emerg- ing economies

grow and develop educational institutions, their stock of managerial capital builds.

To bridge the gap in the meantime, they can import foreign managers, copy the

best practices of multinational managers, or hire consulting firms to increase

managerial capital.

Industrialization and Population Growth

There is no doubt that industrialization is responsible for the massive increase in

world population over the past two centuries. During the early Industrial

Revolution, the British were able to maintain their living stan- dards despite rapid

population growth because industrialization and inter- national trade created such

robust demand for their domestic labor. In the early-19th century, after the

Industrial Revolution ignited in Britain then spread elsewhere, there were one

billion people on the planet, compared to over seven billion today. Just in the past

50 years, the world population has doubled (although world population growth

rates have steadily declined after peaking in the 1960s). All developing nations go

through the “demographic transition” process: first death rates decline due to

better living conditions and medical care, and thereafter birth rates fall due to

lower infant mortality rates and more work opportunities for women. Economic

development also extends life expectancy. Today it ranges from about 80 years at

birth in the United States, Japan, and much of Europe, to 50 years in parts of

Africa, such as Zimbabwe and Somalia.

Theory of Globalization and Labor Markets

In canonical economic growth models, wages increase as economies develop.

Emerging economies accumulate capital and improve their tech- nologies, thereby

increasing labor productivity and boosting labor demand and wages. At the same

time, an increased labor supply resulting from population growth puts downward

pressure on wages during the industri- alization process. By and large, the

evidence suggests development leads to higher wages in spite of population

growth, at least after a Lewis turning